CREDIT Research Paper
No. 00/11

 

Explaining Growth: A Contest between Models

 

By Michael Bleaney and Akira Nishiyama
Centre for Research in Economic Development and International Trade, University of Nottingham

 

The Authors
Michael Bleaney is Professor and Akira Nishiyama is Research Student, both in the School of Economics, University of Nottingham.

August 2000

 

Abstract

Recent contributions to the empirical growth literature show no tendency to convergence in specification, as researchers seek to identify new variables that can account for significant regional effects in earlier work. We conduct non-nested tests between the models of Barro (1997), Easterly and Levine (1997) and Sachs and Warner (1997). The data strongly prefer an encompassing model, but fail to reject any of the candidate models, implying that each model represents a partial truth. We identify a model that includes most (but not all) of the regressors in the candidate models and is robust to the inclusion of regional dummies.

 

I. INTRODUCTION

The empirics of growth has itself been a growth area of research in the last fifteen years, stimulated by new theoretical developments and new data bases. In an article published in 1992, Levine and Renelt noted the proliferation of explanatory variables in published growth regressions, and attempted to introduce some order into the discussion by identifying the variables which were robustly significant across specifications. This exercise has since been repeated with a different methodology and somewhat different results (Sala-i-Martin, 1997). Nevertheless empirical growth research has continued to show a strong tendency towards further proliferation of alternative specifications, and not of convergence towards an agreed specification. New variables such as ethno-linguistic diversity, measures of institutional quality, and the share of primary products exports in GNP have been found to be statistically significant in growth regressions (Easterly and Levine, 1997; Sachs and Warner, 1997).

This trend towards divergence has been driven by several factors. One is that investment (one of Levine and Renelt’s few robust variables) has increasingly been seen as endogenous to growth, and therefore part of what needs to be explained rather than part of the explanation (e.g. Barro, 1997, pp. 32-3). A second factor is that the statistical significance of regional dummy variables (e.g. for sub-Saharan Africa) in Barro’s (1991) regression has been regarded as evidence of omitted regressors and therefore as a challenge to be met by finding more acceptable alternatives. Thirdly, of course, researchers are continually having new ideas and finding new data. The purpose of the present paper is to test how some recent models, with different specifications, match up against one another when tested on the same data set. The point of the exercise is that these models contain very different explanatory variables. The models tested are those of Sachs and Warner (1997) (whose data set we use), Barro (1997) and Easterly and Levine (1997). Our main conclusion is that we can improve considerably on any one of these models by adding elements from the others. This is encouraging in the sense that new models are offering genuine value added.

 

II. THE COMPETING MODELS

We consider three models that have figured in the recent empirical growth literature: those of Barro (1997), Easterly and Levine (1997) and Sachs and Warner (1997). Barro’s model is an update of his earlier work (Barro, 1991), but using a panel of ten-year average growth rates instead of a pure cross-section. The main innovations in his 1997 specification are the inclusion of male (but not female) secondary and higher schooling, a rule of law index, an index of democracy and its square, and an interactive term between male schooling and initial per capita income. Easterly and Levine (1997) [EL hereafter] emphasise the role of ethnic diversity or fractionalisation (defined as the probability that two randomly chosen individuals belong to different ethnic groups). They also include a measure of financial depth and a quadratic term in initial per capita income, together with a number of other variables from Barro’s earlier work. They too use a panel of three ten-year averages. Sachs and Warner (1997) [SW hereafter] emphasise openness to international trade, the share of primary products in exports, exposure to a tropical climate and landlockedness, as well as more standard variables. Their data set is a pure cross-section of 1965-90 average growth rates.

Table 1. Specification of alternative growth models

Variable

Sign of effect
on growth

Barro

EL

SW

Initial per capita income (Y)

-

*

*

*

Square of Y

-

 

*

 

Openness

+

   

*

Openness * Y

-

   

*

Black market premium

-

 

*

 

Schooling

+

 

*

 

Male schooling

+

*

   

Male schooling * Y

-

*

   

Financial depth

+

 

*

 

Inflation rate

-

*

   

Fertility rate

-

*

   

Central gov’t
savings/GDP

+

 

*

*

Gov’t consumption/GDP

-

*

   

Life expectancy

+

*

 

*

Life expectancy squared

-

   

*

Rule of law index

+

*

   

Institutional quality

+

   

*

Assassinations

-

 

*

 

Democracy index

+

*

   

Democracy index squared

-

*

   

Terms of trade growth

+

*

   

Primary product exports/GDP

-

   

*

Tropical climate

-

   

*

Landlockedness

-

   

*

Economically active minus total pop. growth

+

   

*

Ethnic diversity

-

 

*

 

Note: * denotes that variable is included in the model’s specification. Barro: Barro (1997); EL -- Easterly and Levine (1997); SW -- Sachs and Warner (1997).

The extent of the variation in the regression specifications of these three models is demonstrated in Table 1. The log of initial per capita GDP is in fact the only one amongst 26 regressors that is common to all three models.1 This variation does not appear to be the consequence of any identifiable theoretical differences between authors. The choice of variables is an empirical decision made by investigators drawing on a common corpus of theory. Using a single data set (that of SW), we investigate whether any of these three models can be rejected in favour of the others, and if not, which variables would be included in an encompassing model that yields a better fit to the data than any of the individual candidates. We begin by performing non-nested tests between each pair of models. This results in six separate tests (see Table 2). The EL model performs considerably less well than others, with a much higher standard error. Nevertheless it still has statistically significant J-statistics (t-statistics of the fitted values) of 2.41 (p<0.02) against the Barro model and 3.61 (p<0.01) against SW. Both of the other two models have J-statistics of at least 5.98 in each test (p<0.001). This constitutes very strong evidence that no single one of the candidate models unambiguously dominates the others. The SW model performs best (not surprisingly, because the tests use their data set and cross-section method), but the Barro model is not far behind, and the results imply that each of these models can be significantly improved by adding at least some elements from the other models. The EL model is clearly inferior to the others in terms of fit, but even this model significantly improves each of the others.

Table 2. Non-nested tests between alternative models
Davidson-MacKinnon J-statistics for pairs of models

Alternative Model:

Barro

Easterly & Levine

Sachs & Warner

No. of obs. In regression

Standard deviation of residuals

Tested Model

         

Barro

 

2.41

7.70

71

0.897

Easterly & Levine

10.44

 

14.36

75

1.28

Sachs & Warner

5.98

3.61

 

84

0.769

Notes: the statistic is the t-statistic of the fitted values of the alternative model listed at the top of the column in an augmented regression in which the other variables are those of the tested model listed in the relevant row. See Davidson and MacKinnon (1981) for details.

Table 3. An encompassing model
Dependent variable: per capita annual growth of PPP-adjusted GDP, 1965-90

Variable

Coefficient (t-statistic)

Source Model

Constant

-32.9
(-3.45)

 

Log 1965 per capita income (Y)

7.36
(3.08)

all

Square of Y

-0.594
(-4.07)

EL

Openness

1.31
(5.20)

SW

Log 1965 life expectancy

2.99
(4.05)

B, SW

Male schooling

0.455
(3.65)

B

Institutional quality

0.403
(6.24)

SW

Democracy index

3.44
(3.54)

B

Democracy index squared

-2.69
(-2.94)

B

Central government saving/GDP

7.69
(3.49)

EL, SW

Government consumption/GDP

-7.32
(-4.10)

B

Primary product exports/GDP

-3.02
(-3.58)

SW

Terms of trade growth

0.216
(4.52)

B

Tropical climate

-0.579
(-2.66)

SW (amended -- see Appendix)

Economically active minus total population growth

0.633
(2.22)

SW

No. of observations

70

 

Adjusted R-squared

0.920

 

Standard error

0.541

 

Notes: B -- Barro (1997); EL -- Easterly and Levine (1997); SW -- Sachs and Warner (1997). For definition of variables see Appendix.

Table 4. Effects of adding further regressors individually to the Table 3 regression
Dependent variable: per capita annual growth of PPP-adjusted GDP, 1965-90

Regressor

No. of observations
in regression

t-statistic of added
variable

Adjusted R-squared

Table 3 model

70

 

0.920

Landlockedness

70

-0.59

0.919

Square of life expectancy

70

-0.66

0.919

Financial depth

69

0.03

0.916

Ethnic diversity

69

-1.21

0.921

Female schooling

70

-0.74

0.919

Fertility

70

1.15

0.920

Male schooling * Y

70

-1.35

0.921

Openness * Y

70

-1.64

0.922

Inflation rate

67

-0.37

0.918

Neighbouring countries’ growth

70

-0.82

0.919

Note: For fuller definition of variables see Appendix.

 

III. AN ENCOMPASSING MODEL

The next stage is to estimate what improvements can be made by combining all the regressors from the three candidate models in an encompassing model, and then eliminating those regressors that are statistically insignificant. The model that results from this process is shown in Table 3. This model omits landlockedness, the square of life expectancy, and the interactive term between openness and income from the SW model, and includes the square of initial per capita income (an EL variable) and also the following Barro variables: male schooling, democracy and its square, terms of trade growth and government consumption. The sample size is reduced to 70, but the adjusted R-squared rises to 0.920, and the standard deviation of the residuals falls to 0.541 (compared with 0.847 and 0.769 respectively for SW, which is estimated on 84 observations).2 This is a considerable improvement.

The model implies that the relationship between growth and initial per capita income has an inverted U-shape (as Easterly and Levine also find), with a maximum at Y = 6.12 [=7.36/(2 x 0.59)]. Since this maximum is below the level of the poorest country in the sample, the implication is that the relationship between income and growth is negative (and with an increasing slope as income increases). The coefficient of openness implies that a country that corresponded to the SW definition of "open to international trade" throughout the 25-year period is estimated to have grown 1.3% p.a. faster than one that was closed throughout the period, or 0.05% p.a. faster for each year of openness.3 Each 1% added to 1965 life expectancy is estimated to add 0.3% to the growth rate. An additional year of schooling for the male population over 25 years adds 0.5% to the growth rate, which is considerably less than Barro’s (1997) estimate of 1.2%. A unit increase in institutional quality (which is measured on a scale of 1 to 6) raises growth by 0.4% p.a., which is intermediate between SW’s estimate of 0.3% and Barro’s estimate of 0.5% for the rule of law index (which is one component of the institutional quality index). The democracy index is measured on a scale of 0 to 1 (1 being the most democratic), and the coefficients indicate a maximum positive effect at a value of 0.65; around this value an increase in the democracy index of 0.1 adds 0.1% to the growth rate.4

We come now to the fiscal variables. These imply that an increase in central government saving by 1% of GDP, or a fall in government consumption expenditure by the same amount (with saving unchanged), each raise growth by 0.075% p.a.5 Lower consumption accompanied by increased saving of 1% of GDP (e.g. because other expenditures and taxation are unchanged) is estimated to raise growth by 0.15% p.a. An extra 10% share of primary product exports in GDP is estimated to reduce the growth rate by 0.3%, whilst each 1% p.a. addition to the trend in the terms of trade adds 0.2% to the growth rate. Location in the tropics reduces the growth rate by 0.6%, whilst each percentage point difference between the growth rates of economically active and total population adds 0.6% to growth.

In Table 4, we show the t-statistics of omitted candidate variables when added individually to the regression in Table 3. Of the EL variables, financial depth is highly insignificant, whilst ethnic diversity has the expected negative coefficient and slightly increases the adjusted R-squared. This is consistent with EL’s results, since they find ethnic diversity to be significantly negative only in some specifications. Landlockedness is now not at all significant, and neither is inflation nor growth of neighbouring countries (a variable suggested in Easterly and Levine, 1998). Female schooling actually has a negative coefficient (as Barro also finds), whilst fertility has a positive one (compared with a significant negative coefficient in Barro, 1997). There is a case for including the interactive variable openness times initial income, with a t-statistic of -1.64, since its inclusion raises the adjusted R-squared from 0.920 to 0.922. Schooling times initial per capita income also raises the adjusted R-squared (to 0.921), but performs slightly worse than openness times income.

As an additional test of the robustness, we have added dummy variables for sub-Saharan Africa, Latin America and the Caribbean, East Asia and the OECD to the model. The results are shown in Table 5. The first column of Table 5 reproduces the Table 3 regression, whilst the second shows the results of adding the regional dummies. Collectively, these dummies are insignificant (p>0.10), and only one (East Asia) has a coefficient that exceeds one regression standard error.

How, therefore, does our equation explain the large differences in average growth rates of different regions over the period? We address this question in Table 6. The Table shows the growth rate of each region, and the estimated contribution of each variable in explaining it, relative to the omitted category (the Mediterranean, Oceania and Asia west of Thailand - MOWA). The first row of Table 6 shows that sub-Saharan Africa (SSA) and Latin America and the Caribbean (LAC) grew at similar rates, but 1.5% p.a. slower than MOWA, 1.8% slower than OECD and 3.6% slower than East Asia (EAS) in per capita terms.

Table 5. Testing for regional effects
Dependent variable: per capita annual growth of PPP-adjusted GDP, 1965-90

Variable

Coefficient
(t-statistic)

Coefficient
(t-statistic)

Constant

-32.9
(-3.45)

-36.3
(-3.72)

Log 1965 per capita income (Y)

7.36
(3.08)

7.89
(3.26)

Square of Y

-0.594
(-4.07)

-0.616
(-4.21)

Openness

1.31
(5.20)

1.19
(3.71)

Log 1965 life expectancy

2.99
(4.05)

3.23
(4.32)

Male schooling

0.455
(3.65)

0.399
(3.16)

Institutional quality

0.403
(6.24)

0.383
(4.89)

Democracy index

3.44
(3.54)

2.79
(2.70)

Democracy index squared

-2.69
(-2.94)

-1.94
(-1.95)

Central government saving/GDP

7.69
(3.49)

7.41
(3.35)

Government consumption/GDP

-7.32
(-4.10)

-6.95
(-3.70)

Primary product exports/GDP

-3.02
(-3.58)

-3.18
(-3.77)

Terms of trade growth

0.216
(4.52)

0.209
(4.16)

Tropical climate

-0.579
(-2.66)

-0.768
(-2.73)

Economically active minus total population growth

0.633
(2.22)

0.454
(1.31)

Sub-Saharan Africa dummy

 

0.234
(0.59)

Latin America and Caribbean dummy

 

-0.009
(-0.03)

East Asia dummy

 

0.671
(1.54)

OECD dummy

 

-0.230
(-0.63)

No. of observations

70

70

Adjusted R-squared

0.920

0.922

Standard error

0.541

0.533

F-test for regional dummies

 

F(4, 51) = 1.45

Notes: for definition of variables see Appendix. The 10% critical value of F(4, 51) is 2.06.

Table 6. Explaining regional differences in growth rates
Differences in growth rates between regions and in the estimated impact of each variable in the Table 3 regression (% p.a.)

 

Sub-Saharan Africa

Latin America & Caribbean

East Asia

OECD

p.c. growth

-1.52

-1.46

+2.16

+0.36

Independent variables

       

Per capita income

+2.32

-0.75

-0.07

-3.32

Openness

-0.09

+0.14

+0.51

+1.04

Life expectancy

-0.72

+0.18

+0.12

+0.78

Male schooling

-0.26

-0.07

+0.10

+0.35

Institutional quality

-0.05

-0.10

+0.63

+1.75

Democracy

-0.16

+0.14

+0.21

+0.21

Central gov’t saving

-0.07

-0.30

-0.09

-0.36

Government consumption

-0.38

+0.07

+0.08

+0.35

Primary product exports/GDP

+0.19

+0.28

+0.47

+0.51

Terms of trade growth

-0.54

-0.53

-0.41

-0.79

Tropical climate

-0.38

-0.35

-0.27

+0.14

Growth rate of econ. active pop.

-0.19

+0.14

+0.28

+0.01

Notes. All numbers are relative to the omitted region (Mediterranean, Oceania and Asia west of Thailand). Figures reflect the data for the full sample of countries (more than 100 for each variable), not just those used in the regression.

The rest of Table 6 indicates how this is explained by the individual variables in the Table 3 regression. Income effects are very large, highly favourable for SSA and highly unfavourable for OECD. Most of the other variables offset this enormous income effect, tending to be least favourable for SSA and most favourable for OECD. East Asia has fast growth, according to this model, because it resembles OECD considerably more closely than other developing countries whilst having a low initial per capita income. East Asia is not in fact an exceptional region in any dimension (except the increase in the proportion of the population which is economically active, whose impact is relatively minor) when the full range of countries is considered, but for a developing region it has high levels of openness, male schooling, institutional quality and measures of democracy and fiscal rectitude. According to the model low initial per capita income should make SSA grow 3% p.a. faster than LAC, other things being equal, but that is offset by inferior values of practically every other variable, especially life expectancy, openness, democracy and the trend in the economically active population.

In summary, our results suggest that most of the new variables that have been introduced into growth regressions in the 1990s survive a rigorous test against alternative models. The ones that do not (landlockedness, growth of neighbouring countries) are arguably those with the weakest theoretical basis. Human capital, institutions, specialisation in primary products, and terms of trade changes all seem to be important determinants of growth, and there is considerable evidence of non-linearity in the relationship between income level and growth.

 

IV. CONCLUSIONS

In this paper we have compared the performance of alternative empirical growth models on a common data set. The purpose of the exercise was not just to match these models against one another, but also to establish a benchmark model that encapsulates the state of current research. We found that the model which best fits the data includes elements from all three of the candidate models considered. This encompassing model provides a framework against which future innovations in empirical growth research may be judged: in introducing previously untried variables, an investigator needs to show that these variables improve the fit even in the presence of the full complement of regressors from our encompassing regression. Otherwise, he or she will have failed to demonstrate that the new variables genuinely outperform old ones.

 

REFERENCES

Barro, Robert J. 1991. Economic growth in a cross-section of countries, Quarterly Journal of Economics 106, 2 (May), 407-33.

Barro, Robert J. 1997. Determinants of Economic Growth: A Cross-Country Empirical Study, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.

Belsley, David A., Edwin Kuh and Roy E. Welsch. 1980. Regression Diagnostics, New York: John Wiley and sons.

Davidson, Russell, and MacKinnon, James G. 1981. Several tests for model specification in the presence of alternative hypotheses, Econometrica 49, 3 (May), 781-93.

Easterly, William, and Levine, Ross. 1997. Africa’s growth tragedy: policies and ethnic divisions, Quarterly Journal of Economics 112, 1203-50.

Easterly, William, and Levine, Ross. 1998. Troubles with the neighbours: Africa’s problem, Africa’s opportunity, Journal of African Economies 7 (1), 120-42.

Levine, Ross, and Renelt, David. 1992. A sensitivity analysis of cross-country growth regressions, American Economic Review 82 (4), 942-63.

Sachs, Jeffrey D., and Warner, Andrew. 1995. Economic reform and the process of global integration, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1, 1-118.

Sachs, Jeffrey D., and Warner, Andrew. 1997. Sources of slow growth in African economies, Journal of African Economies 6, 3 (October) 335-76.

Sala-i-Martin, Xavier. 1997. I just ran two million regressions, American Economic Review 87, 2 (May), 178-83.

 

APPENDIX

The following table lists the data sources and the precise designation of the variable in the data source. SW denotes Sachs and Warner (1997), and BL denotes Robert J. Barro and Jong-Wha Lee, Data Set for a Panel of 138 Countries (1994). The non-nested tests are based on the original SW model, but in estimating the encompassing model we made three minor modifications. (1) We replaced 1970 life expectancy by 1965 life expectancy, to avoid any possible endogeneity problems. (2) We amended the landlockedness variable, defining Jordan and Zaire, which do in fact have access to the sea, as not landlocked. (3) We amended the tropical climate variable (whose meaning in SW is never entirely clear) so that it more accurately represents the proportion of the country that falls between the Tropics of Cancer and Capricorn. This involves some significant reclassifications including Hong Kong as 1 (not 0), Egypt as 0.2 (not 1) and Bangladesh as 0.5 (not 0.1), and rectifying some omissions in the SW data set for this variable. A full list of these amendments is available from the authors on request.

Variable

Data source

Variable designation in source

Per capita growth 1965-90

SW

G6590

Per capita income in 1965 (log)

SW

LGDPEA65

Openness (dummy variable)

SW

OPEN6590

Black market premium average 1970-90

Sachs and Warner (1995)

BMP

Male schooling (secondary plus higher) 1965

BL

SYRM65 + HYRM65

Female schooling (secondary plus higher) 1965

BL

SYRF65 + HYRF65

Financial depth, ave. 1965-90

BL

LLY

Inflation rate, average 1965-90

SW

INFL6590

Fertility rate 1965

BL

FERT65

Central gov’t savings/GDP

SW

CGB7090

Government consumption/GDP

BL

GVXDXE

Life expectancy in 1965 (log)

SW

LIFEE065

Institutional quality

SW

ICRGE80

Assassinations per capita

SW

ASSASSP

Democracy

Barro (1997)

DEMOCRACY 1975

Terms of trade growth 1965-90

Authors

TOTGR (constructed from World Bank data)

Primary product exports

SW

SXP

Tropical climate

SW

TROPICS

Tropical climate (amended)

Authors

CLIMATE

Landlockedness

SW

ACCESS

Landlockedness (amended)

Authors

INLAND

Economically active minus total population growth

SW

GEAP-POP

Ethnic diversity

SW

ETHLING

Neighbour countries’ growth

SW

G7089N

 

1 | Nevertheless some of the variables are closely related. For example the black market premium is a component of SW’s measure of openness, and Barro’s rule of law index and SW’s measure of institutional quality are drawn from the same source.

2 | SW prefer to omit five countries (Botswana, Gabon, Madagascar, Guyana and Israel) as outliers, which substantially improves the fit, yielding an adjusted R-squared of 0.890 and a standard error of 0.628. Their technique for identifying outliers (that of Belsley et al., 1980) is however model-specific. In comparing alternative models, it is therefore correct to include these five observations, which might not be identified as outliers with a different model.

3 | A country has to be non-socialist, not have an export marketing board, have average tariffs and coverage of non-tariff barriers each below 40%, and have a black market exchange rate premium of less than 20% to be classified as open.

4 | The industrial countries all have a value of one. Compared with a value of zero, a value of one adds 0.7% to the growth rate.

5 | The definition of consumption excludes education and defence expenditures.