BALANCING:
POLICIES FOR JUST AND SUSTAINABLE TRADE
By Kristin Dawkins
Institute for Agriculture and Trade Policy
Minneapolis, Minnesota 55404 USA
Tel: 612-870-0453
Fax: 612-870-4846
E-Mail: iatp@iatp.org
Third Revision: January 1994.
United Nations Conference on Environment and Development (UNCED.)
________________________________
______________________________________________________________________________
Trade can be positive. The benefits of exchanging goods and services
as a way of sharing the world's wealth are obvious. Some crops,
like coffee, grow only in special climates. Certain raw materials,
such as petroleum, are found unevenly scattered across the globe.
In order to share products like coffee and petroleum, corporate
exporters and importers from different geographic regions engage
in trade.
Trade can also be negative. Trade in human beings, slavery, is
immoral and unjust. Trade in products which endanger human health
or the environment and trade practices which make some people
rich by impoverishing others are certainly unwise and unjust.
Trade-related impoverishment -- of people, of nations and of the
planet -- results from imbalances in four key areas. To achieve
sustainable trade policies, we must restore balance to each: the
balance of trade, the terms of trade, the price-cost ratio, and
social/ecological accounts. To do so, it is crucial to remember
that governments do not trade, corporations do. The role of governments,
whether national or international, is to set the rules which regulate
corporate trade and to manage the distribution of trade-generated
wealth.
Balance #1 - "Balance of Trade":
The balance of trade measures whether the export earnings of all
the corporations based in a particular nation cover the total
cost of its corporations' imports. When total import costs exceed
the value of exports, the country has a trade deficit and its
supply of foreign currency may fall short. Then it is forced to
make up the difference through borrowing from private lenders
such as transnational banks or from government lenders such as
the International Monetary Fund.
Balance #2 - "Terms of Trade":
The terms of trade is a ratio that compares the prices received
by a country's corporations for its exports to the prices it pays
for its imports: the price of coffee beans to the price of a tractor,
for example. Deterioration of a country's terms of trade means
that, over time, it is able to import less in exchange for the
same amount of exports; in other words, each year fewer tractors
can be purchased with the revenues from its annual coffee bean
harvest. This is an impoverishing trend -- similar to the hardship
caused a family when inflation increases faster than household
income.
For less-industrialized countries, the terms of trade have deteriorated
-- meaning that in world markets, the prices paid for their raw
material and agricultural exports have fallen while the prices
of their processed goods imports have increased. The terms of
trade affect the rate at which nations must convert their natural
resources to tradeable products.
Deterioration in the terms of trade is caused by a wide variety
of practices and policies. For example, oversupply in the world
market can cause prices to fall while a shortage -- due to weather,
war or other factors -- can cause prices to rise. Exchange rate
and interest rate shifts also alter a nation's economic relationship
to the world market. Monopoly suppliers, too, can manipulate prices.
And external shocks such as a sudden rise in oil prices can change
the terms of trade dramatically.
Balance #3 - "Price-Cost Ratio":
The price-cost ratio compares the prices paid to the producers
of exported goods to their costs of producing those goods. When
producers do not receive prices to cover their full costs of production
-- including fair wages, a fair profit for reinvestment and all
social and ecological costs for all stages in the cycle of that
production process -- the producer faces a deficit.
Balance #4 - "Social / Ecological Accounts":
Trade-related social and ecological accounts are a means of expressing
the costs/value of protecting and regenerating the human and natural
resources used in the importing and exporting of goods and services.
These accounts are in balance when society collects -- through
market mechanisms or taxes -- and reinvests the full value of
these expenses to replenish and sustain its resources.
The value of natural resources in their unexploited state is not
reflected in measures of national wealth. Environmental costs
such as cleaning up pollution or public investments in waste disposal
are generally not reflected in market prices. By shifting the
burden to the public sector, industry escapes these costs -- called
"externalities" because the costs are external to the
market economy.
Unless both social and ecological accounts are recognized and
balanced, future generations face environmental deficits from
pollution and depleted natural resources as well as ever greater
deficits in their health, educational, welfare, cultural and other
institutions.
The First Stage of Imbalance - Unbalanced Trade:
When any of the key elements are not in balance, deficits are
created. Deficits must be covered by borrowing. Borrowing against
the future is only reasonable when adequate resources are anticipated
with which to replenish accounts. Chronic debt is the second state
of trade imbalance.
The Second Stage of Imbalance - Debt:
Deficits can be immediately apparent, as in regularly reported
data about a nation's official trade balance. Or they can become
apparent only over time, as in the case of the depletion of natural
resources.
A government's first response to a deficit in the balance of trade
is likely to be an attempt to encourage companies to increase
their exports in hopes of bringing into the country more foreign
currency. Where the economy is largely dependent upon natural
resource exports, the result may be intensified exploitation of
the environment. This not only creates long-term problems, it
can be counterproductive. For example, if agricultural resources
are converted to export-oriented production, local supplies of
food may dry up making communities dependent upon imports for
food -- adding to the trade imbalance.
When an export strategy fails, countries become desperate for
money and are forced into greater debt. But instead of investing
in the future -- such as in developing local industries -- the
new funds are usually spent to cover the immediate deficit. The
draining effect continues and the deficit grows.
The Third Stage of Imbalance - Aid:
Eventually, the debt becomes unpayable. At this point, some rich
nations choose to support the debtor nation's economy as donors
of aid -- cash or goods which can help keep people alive and minimize
social rebellion. However, in most cases this assistance does
not contribute to offsetting the trade-debt-aid spiral. In fact,
aid can perpetuate imbalances. Food aid, for example, competes
with local farmers and gradually reduces a nation's capacity to
feed itself -- thus increasing dependence upon further aid.
To avoid the trade-debt-aid spiral, it is necessary to find policies
that will alter the practices causing the imbalances in each of
the four major areas. In most cases, changes in policy and practice
will affect several balances at once. In the case of trade, this
discussion applies to regional trade negotiations and the international
commodity agreements as well as the GATT, the General Agreement
on Tariffs and Trade. However, we emphasize the GATT policies
because they are global.
In December 1993, more than 100 governments announced to the world
that they had concluded the 8-year process of controversial negotiations
called the Uruguay Round. The new rules of the Uruguay Round agreement
will replace the current rules of the GATT in July 1995 for governments
choosing to join the new World Trade Organization (WTO.) The Uruguay
Round agreement creates this new international institution with
a "legal personality" similar to the World Bank and
the International Monetary Fund.
The World Trade Organization will have the power to require a
member nation "to ensure the conformity of its laws, regulations
and administrative proceedings with its obligations as provided"
in the Uruguay Round agreement. The WTO's assumption of power
presents a strong challenge to national sovereignty and the practice
of democracy. The preservation of democratic rights in international
negotiations is fundamental to whether humanity uses its wisdom
to make the needed changes in trade and other policy that will
restore the earth's economic, social and ecological balances.
Balancing #1 - The Balance of Trade:
In order to solve any imbalance of trade, planners must consider
both the volume and value of imports and both the volume and value
of exports for a given country.
What can be done to reduce the volume of imports, such
as boosting purchases from domestic industries? What can be done
to reduce the prices of imports by increasing efficiencies and
direct negotiations with suppliers for longer term, lower priced
contracts? Where could barter arrangements fit in? If there is
a world market available, what steps are needed to sustain production
available for exporting? If export prices are too low, what international
or bilateral arrangements can be made to boost world prices? What
can be done to stabilize currency exchange rates?
Unfortunately, the new World Trade Organization will obligate
nations to import certain minimum percentages of basic commodities
and lock-in low world prices for exported agricultural products.
And recently, nations have allowed exchange rate fluctuations
to become increasingly volatile. Nations should re-evaluate the
prices of basic goods in the global market, including the price
of money itself.
Balancing #2 - Terms of Trade:
Deteriorating terms of trade can be caused by a decline in the
price of exports, an increase in the price of imports, or both.
To address this situation requires action on both sides: to raise
the price of exports and reduce the price of imports. Perhaps
the decline in export prices is due to oversupply in the world
markets that can only be solved by global management of stocks.
Perhaps the increase in import prices is due to the presence of
monopoly controls leading to restrictive, unfair business practices.
Perhaps there are currency problems that contribute to this problem.
Most immediately, improving the terms of trade of less-industrialized nations requires valuing their exports more highly. A variety of macroeconomic policy changes would help to do so, as would fair wages and prices that internalize the social and ecological costs of production. Price support programs could ensure that natural resource products reflect their full value; examples include the European Community's "STABEX" system, which distributes pooled funds to stabilize volatile segments of the market, and the commodity agreements in which producer-exporting countries and consumer-importing countries agree
to manage supply and demand. Policies enabling the development
of value-added processing industries would also improve the
terms of trade and eliminate the economic pressure to exploit
increasingly scarce resources.
Unfortunately, the new World Trade Organization rules require
sharp cuts in family farm support programs, including price stabilization
programs. The new rules also prohibit most quantitative import
restrictions which are employed in successful supply-management
programs such as that of Canada. These controls are often needed
to facilitate the development of value-added processing industries.
Minimizing exchange rate fluctuations is especially critical
to balancing the terms of trade. Exchange rates are based on the
purchasing power of each currency in the world financial markets
relative to the dollar, the mark or the yen. Governments can choose
to alter the value of their own currency but, more often, the
International Monetary Fund and World Bank stipulate that a nation
must devalue its currency -- an act which makes its exports more
attractive but obliges the country to exploit its natural and
land resources in greater quantities to earn the same amount of
export revenue.
Exchange rate fluctuations can be stabilized through cooperation.
Cooperating governments can price their currencies according to
a set "basket of goods." This means that the costs of
certain consumer goods are added up for each country; by comparing
these costs from one country to another, equivalent values are
found. When a particular country's currency gains or loses more
than a certain percentage of its value relative to the basket
of goods, the government makes an adjustment. It was through a
system like this that prices remained relatively stable throughout
the European Community during years in which the US dollar fluctuated
wildly.
Successful exchange rate management requires coordination with
other macroeconomic policies --such as interest rates and government
spending. Macroeconomic cooperation and the coordinated adjustment
of currency exchange rates are prerequisites for stabilizing economies
and reducing the pressure on many nations to continuously increase
their exports of natural resource-based products as a response
to a weakening currency.
Balancing #3 - Price-Cost Ratios:
As in both trade balance and terms of trade issues, there are
many factors that can be adjusted to bring prices received for
specific products into line with the cost of production. Again,
currency exchange issues are especially important.
Imbalances between supply and demand result from a variety of circumstances -- especially overproduction in the industrialized countries. Gluts cause prices to fall, preventing many producers from earning enough to meet their costs of production and preventing Third World producers from gaining access to world markets. The elimination of small-scale local producers in this way leads to chronic food shortages in many countries. The lack of economic alternatives also intensifies the depletion of natural resources and land use. On the other hand, shortages caused by circumstances such as drought or war can cause prices to soar, resulting in severe hardships for buyers. GATT Article XI allows governments to implement supply-management programs in conjunction with import restrictions; the Uruguay Round agreement eliminates this provision.
Global supply and demand can be regulated through equitable
systems of shared production. When gluts in world stocks threaten
to depress prices, nations could cooperate in reducing their shares
of production proportionately. Each nation should ensure its own
domestic food self-sufficiency and determine its own method for
meeting national production goals. At the same time, food and
other necessities must be stored on a global basis with an equitable
system for distribution and shared costs to ensure food supplies
in times of scarcity.
Economic dumping is the practice of selling exports at
prices below the real cost of production. Although the dumping
of agricultural products is illegal under GATT Article VI, there
are many ways in which dumping occurs. In the US, for example,
farmers absorb losses that enable exporters to dump their produce
overseas. The dumping of agricultural products overseas eliminates
the ability of many local farmers in the recipient countries to
compete.
In attempting to sustain farm income, many producers will be unable
to practice traditional land conservation techniques and they
may increase their use of pesticides and other chemicals -- leading
to deforestation, erosion, soil destruction and harm to watersheds.
Some will give up trying to compete with dumped imports and abandon
their farms -- leading to increased urbanization and the transformation
of their farms to chemical-intensive export-oriented enterprises.
The loss of more and more local food suppliers causes an increased
reliance on food imports and aid.
The new World Trade Organization should enforce the existing
GATT rules which prohibit agricultural dumping.
Monopolistic and restrictive business practices refer to
an array of mechanisms used by transnational investors to affect
prices and the supply of goods. Price fixing, the allocation of
markets, exclusive deals, and differential or predatory pricing
are just a few of the practices which restrict the ability of
smaller companies to compete and defeat local development. One
of the most troublesome is "transfer pricing," a term
for the manipulation of prices within the operations of transnational
corporations enabling them to minimize their participation in
the economic development of host countries. For example, they
may transfer the accounts for intra-firm activity from a location
in one country to another country in order to take advantage of
currency exchange rate fluctuations. Or they may under-invoice
exports and over-invoice imports, enabling them to evade certain
national regulations.
The new World Trade Organization should not prevent nations
from regulating the behavior of private corporations in order
to meet national development goals. The WTO should encourage multilateral
codes of practice for transnational corporations to stabilize
regulatory policies and provide a predictable business climate
for responsible enterprises. Transnational corporations should
recognize the national law of host countries. Intra-firm transfers
within transnational corporations should be subject to local regulation
and international monitoring.
Balancing #4 - "Social and Ecological Accounts":
Most social and environmental costs and values are external to
the market economy. As a result, products are sold at prices below
the actual cost of production -- a practice called social and
ecological dumping. Long ignored or denied by classical economists,
the impact of creating a deficit in human resource utilization
and natural resource accounts is now more commonly recognized.
The costs of cleaning up and avoiding pollution, disposing of
wastes, paying fair wages, maintaining the health and welfare
of the producing community, and sustaining the value of a nation's
natural resource base should be included in market prices and
national accounting systems. Regulations requiring companies to
pay for health insurance or pollution prevention directly are
one approach to solving this problem. Another approach is through
taxation such as carbon emission taxes, which increase with any
increase in the release of global warming gases. The key issues
are determining the costs that must be borne, the mechanism for
collecting the money, the procedures for ensuring that company
and tax revenues are re-invested in protecting and regenerating
human and natural resources, and the appropriate institutional
mechanism for balancing and adjusting the impacts of a complex
policy.
The external environmental and social costs of production should
be internalized in prices and the definition of dumping should
be expanded to include social and ecological dumping. The sale
of exports at prices below the full cost should be penalized.
Governments should permit compensatory or countervailing social
and ecological tariffs to counteract dumping, with revenues allocated
to correct the incentive to dump. A diverse array of institutional
responses should be encouraged to ensure the precise targeting
of impacts. International mechanisms should be based upon national
and local institutions to ensure that the determination of social
and environmental costs reflects the environmental and social
values of affected communities. The United Nations Environment
Programme, the UN Commission on Sustainable Development and the
new World Trade Organization should collaborate in the design
of international policy which balances trade impacts with social
and environmental impacts.
Discriminatory treatment of processed products refers to
the use of higher tariffs by industrialized countries on imports
of processed products than on the unprocessed version, with the
purpose of protecting their domestic processing industries. For
example, most industrialized countries place higher tariffs on
instant coffee than on raw coffee beans. As a result, the coffee
exporting country must continue exporting beans, foregoing the
revenues that could be gained in processing. For economic growth,
then, the coffee-exporting nations have no choice but to devote
more land to raw coffee production -- often clearing more forests
or farming more hillsides.
The Uruguay Round agreement reduces tariffs overall by 30%;
as a result, discriminatory tariffs will be reduced proportionately.
The new World Trade Organization should prohibit discriminatory
tariff structures which perpetuate impoverishment. Nations should
apply equivalent tariffs for products with equivalent raw natural
resource contents.
Quantitative restrictions on the importing and exporting
of natural resources are an important conservation measure, yet
the Uruguay Round agreement severely limits the use of this option.
Canadian restrictions on salmon and herring exports, for example,
would have helped prevent overfishing but, based on charges by
the US of unfair protection of the Canadian fishing industry,
they were overturned by the GATT. Similarly, Japan objected to
a US ban on the export of logs cut from public land and the European
Community objected to Indonesia's ban on the export of raw logs
and rattan, claiming unfair competition with their respective
furniture industries. Although these cases were not pursued to
the level of a GATT panel, the threat was sufficient to convince
Indonesia to revoke its ban. The result is intensified export
of the raw materials.
Domestically determined quantitative restrictions on natural
resource exports should be permitted as effective conservation
measures. The new World Trade Organization should explicitly interpret
GATT Article XX to exempt conservation and other environmental
protection measures from the definition of trade-distorting non-tariff
barriers. The burden of proof for demonstrating injury as a result
of trade distortion due to environmental measures should rest
with the complainant. The United Nations Environment Programme,
the UN Commission on Sustainable Development and the new World
Trade Organization should collaborate in the design of compensatory
mechanisms to facilitate economic adjustment.
Democratic governance depends upon transparent decisionmaking
processes involving the smallest appropriate political units.
Yet the new World Trade Organization has the power to overrule
national as well as local laws. Under the Uruguay Round rules,
the World Trade Organization can oblige countries to revise certain
national, state and local laws -- such as regulations for pesticides,
logging from public lands, recycled paper content, automobile
emissions or nutrition labeling -- to minimize their "trade
restrictive" effects or to bring them into compliance with
often weaker international standards.
Disputes resulting from the Uruguay Round agreement will be decided
by panels of trade experts appointed by governmental officials
-- panels that operate with no transparency or accountability.
The rules actually prohibit panel appointees from releasing documents
and from disclosing their opinions to the public. Ongoing negotiation
of trade policy, too, is typically conducted in secret by unaccountable
trade experts with no environmental or other expertise. At times,
even some affected governments are excluded from negotiations
while participating governmental officials refuse to discuss proposals
in public.
Sanctions and cross-retaliation are the enforcement mechanisms
to be employed by the new World Trade Organization. When a dispute
panel judges that a country's domestic law does not comply with
the rules of the Uruguay Round agreement, the losing country is
supposed to change its law within a reasonable period of time.
If it fails to do so, the winning country can retaliate by asking
the WTO for permission to suspend a certain amount of its trade
with the loser. For example, if a country refuses to change a
food-related law judged to be illegal, it could lose opportunities
to trade in agricultural products with the other country -- or
pay an equivalent monetary compensation. If this penalty is not
sufficiently effective, then the winning country can "cross-retaliate"
with sanctions against industrial products and other perhaps more
costly sectors of the economy.
Retaliatory trade sanctions can be very powerful instruments.
In fact, the mere threat of sanctions is often sufficient to convince
countries to change their laws or other trade practices. However,
the effectiveness of sanctions is relative to each country's economic
dependence, market shares and the import sensitivity; both trading
partners can be hurt by the lost economic activity, a smaller
country with a weaker economy that is relatively dependent upon
trade is much more vulnerable than a larger country that controls
a significant share of the world market. Therefore, even when
a small country wins a dispute and is authorized to retaliate
against the violator, its citizens may suffer if the sanctions
are employed.
One of the stated goals of the World Trade Organization is "achieving
greater coherence in economic policymaking" with the International
Monetary Fund and the World Bank. Yet these institutions are notorious
for escalating the number and severity of conditions -- called
"conditionalities" -- that are demanded of impoverished
nations at each of the stages from trade to debt to aid.
One of the most common conditions imposed is open access to the
debtor's consumer markets. Of course, this does nothing to develop
the local productive economy nor does it counteract the spiraling
trade-debt-aid imbalances. With each escalation along the spiral,
nations are less able to support an export economy, debt service,
and conditionalities, as well as the needs of their citizens.
Frequently, lenders and donors demand that countries comply with
a large number of economic austerity conditions simultaneously
to qualify for new loans and aid. Called "structural adjustment
programs" or "SAPs," such packages of conditions
usually include devaluing a nation's currency exchange rate to
promote exports, reducing the domestic budget and privatizing
industry and the service sector.
The International Monetary Fund and the World Bank, the lenders
that most often impose these conditions, claim that their purpose
is to make the economy more efficient. The overall effect, however,
is a transfer of economic wealth and political decisionmaking
away from the local communities.
In addition to precluding national and local economic development,
actual structural adjustment programs have weakened the ability
of many nations to afford environmental protection. Yet, despite
this record, current proposals for international environmental
policy often include "green conditionalities"
defining how countries must behave if they wish access to the
financial resources that may become available for investments
in environmental technologies and environmental management.
The temptation to try to guarantee environmental protection by
imposing conditions on new investments, debt, or aid, can actually
cause further environmental problems. First, green programs or
green conditionalities usually ignore a nation's development,
the economic foundation upon which environmental protection programs
must be based. Second, they tend to replicate the draining effects
of debt and structural adjustment programs that actually prevent
nations from undertaking environmental programs in the first place.
The worst environmental problem with green conditionality, though,
is that the penalty accrues not only to the offending government
but to the entire world. In other words, the penalty for violating
a green conditionality is either the withdrawal of existing resources
or the denial of additional resources. But without resources neither
the government nor its citizens can comply with environmental
protection treaties. As a result, the exploitation of natural
resources and polluting behaviors continue unabated. In fact,
in response to the greater economic distress, it probably worsens.
All conditionalities interfere with the democratic process within
nations. Governments that are obliged to respond to other countries'
governments or to international institutions are less able to
respond to domestic interests. As trade negotiations establish
international policies that actually preempt national, state and
local laws, the loss of democratic participation in government
becomes complete.
Many aspects of the Uruguay Round agreement and ongoing trade
negotiations will preempt national democratic policies and eliminate
the rights of individual citizens to participate in decisions
affecting their lives.
Harmonization refers to the process of setting uniform
standards for imported and exported goods -- eliminating the right
of nations and local communities to establish regulations that
might be stronger than an international norm. Theoretically, harmonized
standards could be based on minimum threshold "floors"
that enable countries to strengthen their own requirements for
safety, health, labor, environmental and human rights. But in
practice, negotiated harmonization proposals tend toward the least
common denominator.
The Uruguay Round agreement, for example, establishes a "ceiling"
for pesticide standards requiring nations to review their domestic
regulations according to norms of Codex Alimentarius, an agency
of the Food and Agriculture Organization. To defend a stronger
standard, countries must attempt to prove matters that really
depend upon subjective judgment. For example, they must prove
that the national or local standard is "scientifically justified;"
that it is "not more trade restrictive than required to achieve
[the] appropriate level of protection;" and that there are
no "unjustifiable distinctions" in risk levels throughout
the country's national and local regulatory systems. In the case
of the US, this could permit pesticide residue levels in certain
foods to rise by factors of ten or more and restore the use of
pesticide products which had previously been banned.
Each nation should retain the right to establish environmental
and social regulations according to domestically determined national
goals. International codes recommending "floors" rather
than "ceilings" can promote minimal standards for community
health and welfare that contribute to each nation's domestic debate
without preempting domestic authority and democratic decisionmaking.
Intellectual property law defined by the World Intellectual
Property Organization under the Paris Convention recognizes nations'
rights to use products with broad social value through mechanisms
such as compulsory licensing. The new trade related intellectual
property rights rules -- called "TRIPs"
-- of the Uruguay Round agreement will allow companies to strengthen
their monopoly of intellectual property through long-term patents
for new technologies. In particular, the new rules will allow
the patenting of life forms and limit access to medicines and
seeds covered by pharmeceutical and agricultural patents. TRIPs
will tend to slow the application of best available environmentally-friendly
technologies and hinder the development of non-resource intensive
industries in the Third World. Furthermore, there is a double
standard. Third World proposals for TRIPs protecting their genetic
resources and indigenous technologies are not recognized in the
Uruguay Round agreement.
There should be no double standard for the protection of intellectual
property. Knowledge should be considered a common heritage to
be shared through education and cooperation. Technology transfer
should be promoted among all nations and communities; it should
include both industrial and indigenous technologies of both the
South and the North. The new World Trade Organization should recognize
intellectual property rights as established by the World Intellectual
Property Organization and the Biodiversity Convention.The patenting
of life forms should be prohibited.
Trade related investment measures, called TRIMS,
will be strictly limited by the World Trade Organization. Many
national and local laws regulating foreign investments will be
considered trade-restrictive and illegal. The resulting drain
of resources from a national economy to foreign investors will
hinder the ability of many countries to promote local development
and environmental protection. A "right to establish"
services in any country, regardless of the impact on domestic
programs, is still pending in follow-up negotiations to the Uruguay
Round. Under this proposal, nations would lose the right to base
their economies on domestic banking, insurance, transportation,
utility, health and other critical service sectors.
Each nation should retain the right to regulate foreign investment and service industries according to domestically determined national goals.
A history of imbalanced trade, spiraling debt and self-perpetuating
aid policies have created unsustainable poverty and ecological
destruction among the nations of the world.
The Uruguay Round agreement creates a new set of trade rules that
extends the GATT's scope to new controversial provisions regarding
agriculture, intellectual property, investment measures, service
industries, health, and conservation, and other matters. The agreement
creates a powerful new institution, the World Trade Organization,
to enforce the new rules which tend to constrain nations from
regulating many aspects of the behavior of trading corporations
-- despite their impact upon peoples' health and the ecosystems
of the planet. The new rules also constrain nations from establishing
price and border policies that can help manage domestic production
and the use of natural resources.
Furthermore, the World Trade Organization will use voting and
binding dispute resolution procedures in place of the present
system of decisionmaking based on consensus between participating
nations. Because economic sanctions are the enforcement mechanism,
only countries with substantial economic power can afford to wield
the weapon of withholding trade. The new rules for cross-retaliation
will give wealthier industrialized countries a stronger means
than ever for overpowering weaker countries with predominantly
natural resource based economies.
The World Trade Organization will extend and strengthen the GATT's
power to overrule national and local governments. The preemption
of domestic authority by multilateral institutions raises
democratic as well as economic and environmental problems. In
close cooperation with the World Bank and the International Monetary
Fund, the WTO can systematically develop policies to override
national decisionmaking institutions regarding the value of currency,
fiscal and monetary policy, domestic budget plans, wage laws,
and even health and environmental policies in order to maximize
the economic opportunities of transnational corporations. With
this further erosion of national sovereignty over the regulation
of transnational corporations, citizens become almost entirely
removed from global decisionmaking on major issues with critical
economic, social and environmental impacts.
The lack of democratic process in trade negotiations is exacerbated
by the lack of transparency. The proceedings of the World
Trade Organization, its dispute panels, and most other trade negotiations
will exclude citizens. Decisions will be made in private and reported
after the fact. Disputes will be settled in secret. By withholding
information from the public, decisionmakers perpetuate the notion
that trade and economic policy is too complicated to be of general
interest.
Nations should insist upon democratic processes of decisionmaking
-- constructing multilateral international policy upon decisions
made at the level of the smallest appropriate political units.
Local communities can best assess their own needs and manage the
wise use of resources to ensure their own and their children's
welfare. The representation of community interests in determining
trade, environmental and social policy should be guaranteed not
only at the national level but internationally .
The evolution of a comprehensive global institution for sustainable
development is desirable -- but it must be democratic, transparent,
equitable, accountable and reflect the diversity of the peoples
of the planet. It must be based upon diverse expertise and
address diverse social and ecological issues as well as a diverse
array of economic issues. Among the policies neglected by the
Uruguay Round agreement are regulation of the restrictive business
practices of transnational corporations, commodity agreements
and the terms of trade, internalization of social and ecological
costs, allocation of revenues from environmental taxes and tariffs
to enable environmentally benign production, and macroeconomic
policies including currency exchange rates and debt.
Achieving sustainable development will require national and international policies that restore balance in four key aspects of the economy. These are the balance of trade, the terms of trade, the price-cost ratio, and social and ecological accounts. To achieve these balances, policies for just and sustainable trade must interrupt the trade-debt-aid spiral that has crippled most nations. Above all, policies for sustainable development must respect local communities and avoid the erosion of culture.
© Institute for Agriculture and Trade Policy
The Institute for Agriculture and Trade Policy was
organized in 1986 to alert US public interest organizations to
the importance of international economic and environmental policymaking
institutions and to provide these organizations with the information,
skills, and access needed to influence global decisionmaking.
The first public event the Institute helped organize was an international
conference on "The Impact of Agricultural Trade on Domestic
Farm Policies" held in Geneva, Switzerland in 1986.
The Institute became one of the first public interest
organizations to monitor the negotiation of the General Agreement
on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) as, in 1986, some 100 countries began
rewriting the international rules of trade. In 1988, the Institute
extended its monitoring, education, technical assistance and organizing
efforts to the US-Canada Free Trade Agreement. That year, the
Institute also sponsored an international conference on agricultural
trade conflicts and a series of panel discussions on "The
Economics of Sustainable Development." In 1990, the Institute
extended its program again to include the negotiation of the North
American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) and the United Nations Conference
on Environment and Development (UNCED.)
Today, the Institute is the hub of a growing network
of public interest organizations concerned with the rapidly expanding
influence of global economic and environmental policymaking institutions.
The Institute builds coalitions among producer, consumer, environmental,
development, farm and labor organizations from many different
countries -- constituencies which are often isolated from each
other. By bringing together unconventional allies, the Institute
is a catalyst for effective action on a broad range of issues.