MIT Scholar Proposes IPR Reform
IPR Info, No. 19
November 23, 1997
The following is a review by IATP’s Kristin Dawkins of Lester Thurow’s article entitled "Needed: A New System of Intellectual Property Rights," printed in the Harvard Business Review, September – October 1997. Lester Thurow is the Jerome and Dorothy Lemelsom Professor of Management and Economics at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology’s Sloan School of Management.
Economist Lester Thurow has written a pathbreaking critique of today’s intellectual property rights (IPR) system. As he puts it, "Fundamental shifts in technology and in the economic landscape are rapidly making the current system of intellectual property rights unworkable and ineffective. Designed more than 100 years ago to meet the simpler needs of an industrial era, it is an undifferentiated, one size-fits-all system."
Thurow opens his argument with the case of a physician who is suing to get a $9 fee from every laboratory that uses a particular test for Down’s Syndrome. Some years ago, he was awarded a patent for observing a relationship between an elevated level of a particular human hormone and a congenital birth defect. His test had too many false positives to be useful, but later developments showed that if his test were used along with two others, they would accurately forecast whether a baby would be born with Down’s Syndrome. If he wins this suit, the cost of testing will more than double.
Thurow comments, "Should the physician who first observed how the existing gene works get some intellectual property rights? Probably. But they should not be the same kind of rights as those granted to someone who invents a new gene to replace the defective one?" His conclusion: "Such distinctions are necessary, yet our patent system has no basis for making them."
Problems with the Old System
In this Harvard Business Review article, Thurow explains four reasons why the old system for IPR doesn’t work:
According to Thurow, "Bill Gates is the perfect symbol of the new centrality of intellectual property. For more than a century, the world’s wealthiest human being has been associated with oil…today, for the first time in history, the world’s wealthiest person is a knowledge worker. In addition, the world’s major growth industries – such as microelectronics, biotechnology, designer made materials, and telecommunications – are brainpower industries." And "any retailer’s future success is apt to be buried in the software of its electronic information and logistics systems rather than in the art of its window displays." Thurow points out that, in the past, "companies were willing to share their technology because it did not seem to be the source of their success and could not be sold for much anyway. But those days are gone." Companies have huge legal departments, he writes, "to defend what they think is their property, but they are also accused of aggressively attacking what others think is theirs in order to create uncertainties, time delays, and higher start up costs for their competitors.
2. The Decline of Public Knowledge. After World War II, Thurow notes, knowledge flowed freely around the world: "The U.S. government paid for most of the basic research and, with the exception of military technologies, encouraged its worldwide dissemination." But things have changed. The United States has lost its economic dominance, and is cutting back on research and development in both real dollars and as a share of total spending. "As a consequence, less new knowledge will be freely available in the public domain." Without stronger systems of protection, trade secrets become a normal business practice. "Articles about research papers whose publication is deliberately delayed often pop up now in the scientific press," Thurow observes. "A recent study found that 73% of private patents were based on knowledge generated by public sources such as universities and nonprofit or government laboratories."
3. The Emergence of New Technologies. "New technologies have both created new potential forms of intellectual property rights (can pieces of a human be patented?) and made old rights unenforceable (when books can be downloaded from an electronic library, what does a copyright mean?)" And what about the all-pervasive software piracy? "We need to differentiate between fundamental advances in knowledge and logical extensions of existing knowledge," Thurow argues. "Inventing a new piece of biology that alters the natural characteristics of plants, animals, or humans is not equivalent to discovering how an existing piece of biology works. What a patent means has to be different in those two areas.
TOWARDS A NEW SYSTEM OF IPR
Thurow suggest that capitalism depends upon enforceable property rights. Just as the enclosure movement abolished common land in England at the time of the Industrial Revolution, he writes, "The world now needs a socially managed enclosure movement for intellectual property rights or it will witness a scramble among the powerful to grab valuable pieces of intellectual property." Thurow offers three principles towards a responsible new system.
DIVERSITY IS THE KEY
Thurow points out a least three reasons why today’s IPR system should be revised to reflect diverse interests.
Third World’s "need to get low-cost pharmaceuticals is not equivalent to its need for low-cost CDs." Today’s IPR system, which treats such needs equally, is neither a good nor a viable system" he asserts. Instead, "different predetermined levels of fees might be internationally imposed on those who want to use what others have invented," depending upon a country’s income level and the particular technology’s significance for meeting human needs.
electronics industry, Thurow argues for a differentiated IPR system offering different levels of monopoly rights. "The first wants speed and short-term protections because most of its money is earned soon after new knowledge is developed. The second wants long-term protection because most of its money is earned after a long period of testing to prove a drug’s effectiveness and the absence of adverse side effects." Nor should individual inventors be treated the same as large corporations. "Let filers decide what type of patent they wish to have. In no other market do we decide that everyone wants and must buy exactly the same product," he proclaims.
In conclusion, Thurow summarizes, "Trying to squeeze today’s developments into yesterdays system of intellectual property rights simply won’t work. One size does not fit all."
One in a series of info sheets on intellectual property rights available from the Institute for Agriculture and Trade Policy, 2105 First Avenue South, Minneapolis, MN 55404, 612-870-0453; fax 612-870-4846; email iatp@iatp.org